Tesys 100

Could taxing robots help tackle income inequality?

05 January 2023

Economists have suggested that a small tax on robots could help companies retain workers.

What if the US placed a tax on robots? The concept has been publicly discussed by policy analysts, scholars, and Bill Gates (who favours the notion). 


Because robots can replace jobs, the idea goes, a stiff tax on them would give firms an incentive to help retain workers, while also compensating for a drop-off in payroll taxes when robots are used. 


Thus far, South Korea has reduced incentives for firms to deploy robots; European Union policymakers, on the other hand, considered a robot tax but did not enact it.


Now, a study by MIT economists scrutinises the existing evidence and suggests the optimal policy in this situation would indeed include a tax on robots, but only a modest one. The same applies to taxes on foreign trade that would also reduce US jobs, the research finds.


"Our finding suggests that taxes on either robots or imported goods should be pretty small," says Arnaud Costinot, an MIT Economist and co-author of a published paper, detailing the findings. 


"Although robots have an effect on income inequality … they still lead to optimal taxes that are modest."


Specifically, the study finds that a tax on robots should range from one percent to 3.7 percent of their value, while trade taxes would be from 0.03 percent to 0.11 percent, given current US income taxes.


"We came into this not knowing what would happen," says Iván Werning, an MIT economist and the other co-author of the study. 


"We had all the potential ingredients for this to be a big tax, so that by stopping technology or trade you would have less inequality, but … for now, we find a tax in the one-digit range, and for trade, even smaller taxes."


A sufficient statistic: Wages
A key to the study is that the scholars did not start with an a priori idea about whether or not taxes on robots and trade were merited. Rather, they applied a "sufficient statistic" approach, examining empirical evidence on the subject.


For instance, one study by MIT Economist Daron Acemoglu and Boston University Economist Pascual Restrepo found that in the US, from 1990 to 2007, adding one robot per 1,000 workers reduced the employment-to-population ratio by about 0.2 percent; each robot added in manufacturing replaced about 3.3 workers, while the increase in workplace robots lowered wages about 0.4 percent.


In conducting their policy analysis, Costinot and Werning drew upon that empirical study and others. They built a model to evaluate a few different scenarios, and included levers like income taxes as other means of addressing income inequality.


"We do have these other tools, though they're not perfect, for dealing with inequality," Werning says. 


"We think it's incorrect to discuss [these] taxes on robots and trade as if they are our only tools for redistribution."


Still more specifically, the scholars used wage distribution data across all five income quintiles in the US – the top 20 percent, the next 20 percent, and so on – to evaluate the need for robot and trade taxes. 


Where empirical data indicates technology and trade have changed that wage distribution, the magnitude of that change helped produce the robot and trade tax estimates Costinot and Werning suggest. This has the benefit of simplicity; the overall wage numbers help the economists avoid making a model with too many assumptions about, say, the exact role automation might play in a workplace.


"I think where we are methodologically breaking ground, we're able to make that connection between wages and taxes without making super-particular assumptions about technology and about the way production works," Werning says. 


"It's all encoded in that distributional effect. We're asking a lot from that empirical work. But we're not making assumptions we cannot test about the rest of the economy."


Costinot adds: "If you are at peace with some high-level assumptions about the way markets operate, we can tell you that the only objects of interest driving the optimal policy on robots or Chinese goods should be these responses of wages across quantiles of the income distribution, which, luckily for us, people have tried to estimate."


Beyond robots, an approach to climate and more
Apart from its bottom-line tax numbers, the study contains some additional conclusions about technology and income trends. Perhaps counterintuitively, the research concludes that after many more robots are added to the economy, the impact that each additional robot has on wages may actually decline. At a future point, robot taxes could then be reduced even further.


"You could have a situation where we deeply care about redistribution, we have more robots, we have more trade, but taxes are actually going down," Costinot says. 


If the economy is relatively saturated with robots, he adds, "That marginal robot you are getting in the economy matters less and less for inequality."


The study's approach could also be applied to subjects besides automation and trade. There is increasing empirical work on, for instance, the impact of climate change on income inequality, as well as similar studies about how migration, education, and other things affect wages. 


Given the increasing empirical data in those fields, the kind of modelling Costinot and Werning perform in this paper could be applied to determine, say, the right level for carbon taxes, if the goal is to sustain a reasonable income distribution.


"There are a lot of other applications," Werning says. "There is a similar logic to those issues, where this methodology would carry through." That suggests several other future avenues of research related to the current paper.


In the meantime, for people who have envisioned a steep tax on robots, however, they are "qualitatively right, but quantitatively off,” Werning concludes.


Print this page | E-mail this page


Tesys 100

This website uses cookies primarily for visitor analytics. Certain pages will ask you to fill in contact details to receive additional information. On these pages you have the option of having the site log your details for future visits. Indicating you want the site to remember your details will place a cookie on your device. To view our full cookie policy, please click here. You can also view it at any time by going to our Contact Us page.